Green
Carbon Taxes are the way to go - the science says
                        May 2019


Click square for index Green


   

CBC “As it Happens” interviewed the Nobel prize winners for Economy on October 8, 2018. The headline online read: “Nobel Prize-winning economist says carbon taxes are the solution to climate change”.

 

I thought I should read more about it. I found a March 2014 review of a book by William Nordhaus, one of the two Nobel prizewinners in 2018, that attracted my attention - The Climate Casino: Risk, Uncertainty, and Economics for a Warming World, Yale University Press, 2013. The review by Robert Repetto of the International Institute for Sustainable Development, IISD, March 2014, gave a tight encouraging summary:

 

“The book’s main messages are that humans are almost certainly causing climate changes unprecedented during the emergence of civilization, mainly by burning fossil fuels, and that the resultant warming is a major threat to societies and the natural world. Climate dynamics may well involve thresholds and tipping points that, if triggered, could make changes self-reinforcing and irreversible. The only genuine solution is to reduce emissions by changing the practices of billions of people, businesses and governments around the world. This can best be done through market mechanisms, specifically by creating an economic penalty or “price” for carbon emissions, either through a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade regime that limits the use of carbon fuels through tradable permits. Either option would be efficient, but the latter affords greater certainty over future emissions. In adopting targets under either policy, governments should consider both potential damages and the costs of reducing emissions, but should be willing to pay an insurance premium to stay on the safe side. Relative safety may be unattainable unless all countries with significant emissions cooperate to reduce them. If they do, climate change can be limited at a relatively low cost, less than one or two per cent of total income; however, waiting to act would be extremely costly.”

 

Repetto went on to add a few critical concerns but sums up his review with a firm nod to the Nordhaus book:

 

“Because of the important issues that it explores and the informative, even-handed way in which it does so, The Climate Casino is highly recommended. People of all backgrounds can learn much from the book about one of the most important issues we face, and Professor Nordhaus should be highly commended for writing it.”

 

I had to read it!

 

First, know that this is a readable and clearly set out book. It is measured and thoughtful. Statements made follow a series of logical developments with data and charts as evidence. Uncertainties are acknowledged and faced. CO2 is a side product, a pollutant or an “externality” in the language of economics, from burning fossil fuel. It is the key player in global warming and related climate change. Given the serious risks of “tipping points” that lead to major irreversible shifts in climate, the wisest strategy is to avoid them. The simplest response is to have the person producing CO2 pay increasingly for using the fossil fuel that “pollutes” on a “polluter pays” model. Then pollution comes with a cost. And the cost is egalitarian – everyone who produces CO2 pays accordingly. Nordhaus shows in this book that involving everyone – and every country - that produces CO2 is important for meeting a temperature rise limit of 2 degrees.

 

But I get ahead of myself. The book develops its policy advice in an orderly manner. It leads from the science, to the models, to the economics, to the costs of various approaches, to getting a realistic cap on carbon emissions, and to policies national and international.

 

Part I of the book explains the origins of climate change. The first three chapters of the book introduce climate change. It is an economic problem because almost everything we do, the economy, releases CO2 into the atmosphere. Yet CO2 is a pollution produced externally to the economics – it is not paid for in the costs of doing business. Stopping CO2 totally is not feasible. But limiting the global temperature increase to a safe level is feasible if everyone pulls back on CO2 production. Nordhaus explains some models used to simulate temperature rise, the uncertainties in them, and also the near unanimity in the direction of the projections. Concentrations of CO2 are rising. Temperature is rising.


Chapter 4 projects climate changes and temperature rises over coming years. The bottom line: without policies to slow it, the average temperature in 2100 will be at least 3½
°C higher than 1900. Sea level can rise up to 2 ft. Hurricanes can get more serious.

 

Chapter 5 talks about “tipping points” as a theory and about some dangerous tipping points in practice. Once the temperature allows arctic ice to go, more heat is absorbed from the sun, leading to a jump in temperature. When a certain point is reached, ocean currents can change direction so that northern Europe is no longer warmed by a warm Gulf Stream ocean current. He warns there will be surprises – and nasty ones given the possibilities.

 

In Part II, the book moves to look at impacts of global warming, noting lesser impacts in “managed systems”, where humans have experience of control, than in “unmanaged systems.” Chapters 6 & 7 look at changes to agriculture and health - these can be manageable. Then chapter 9 looks at impacts of rising sea levels, ocean acidification, and hurricane intensification. These are hard to manage. Chapter 10 considers impacts that are much harder to manage - damage to wildlife and to natural ecosystems. Nordhaus notes that the Copenhagen 2 degree limit is too low when one considers the high costs of attaining it. But at the same time this limit is too high if the earth has already crossed the threshold of some dangerous tipping points. The book dates from 2013. By 2018, and an international conference later, a figure of 1.5 degrees was indeed considered a wiser target. Yet a cost analysis shows this to be difficult to attain.

 

Part III examines strategies and costs for slowing climate change. Chapter 13 explores adaptation and geoengineering. Adaptation is learning to live with climate change. However dealing with needed crop changes or frequent clean up from floods is not without costs. Some of the most important dangers are unmanageable. Ocean carbonization and ecosystem losses cannot just be adapted to. Geoengineering supposes that technology could slow or stop climate change. In theory, this could be done at a modest cost, but the effectiveness is questionable and the side effects unknown. Nordhaus likens geoengineering to “salvage” therapy in medicine – something used only when all else fails. Reducing the levels of CO2 production is preferable.

 

Chapter 14 examines options for “mitigation” to reduce CO2 production. Some are now available and there are some hoped-for future technologies. Slowing the economy will work now, but is painful. Cutting energy use will work now, but people resist changes to their lifestyle, and their car travel is a big component of CO2 production. Some mitigation like sequestering CO2 from the atmosphere is viable on a small scale at a particular factory but it is questionable given the large scale removal that is needed. Mitigation can reduce CO2 production if well managed.

 

Chapter 15 turns to the costs of slowing climate change I found this new and helpful. Nordhaus takes the three ways of mitigating CO2 production worth considering: curb our carbon intensive activities; produce goods and services with low carbon technologies or fuels; sequester or take out CO2 produced by the combustion. The book moves to the cost – the dollars per ton of CO2 removed. Substituting natural gas for coal in producing electricity is vastly cheaper overall for CO2 removal than buying a more efficient refrigerator. Natural gas conversion costs $20 per ton of CO2 removed compared with $167 per ton removed by producing a more efficient refrigerator. In any example of mitigation, a higher cost needs to be paid up front. You pay more for a hybrid car that mitigates by using less gasoline. How much more it costs depends on the effectiveness of the policy used. Given the cost, policies to reduce CO2 emissions need incentives. Removing coal is king when it comes to reducing CO2 emissions. Yet the favourite policies of governments regulate, or not, the energy efficiency of cars and appliances.

I add that changing electricity generation from coal was done in Ontario with a significant drop in CO2 production, but with a cost on electricity bills and a political cost. In Ontario, the current largest growth of CO2 production is in the transportation sector – the cars and trucks driven and the aircraft flying. See my article August 2018.

 

Ultimately the issue is paying the cost for the entire economy of reducing CO2 production. Nordhaus points out that because the costs of mitigating CO2 production are potentially big, it is important to craft inexpensive ways to reduce emissions and to ensure societies use them – as in the example of natural gas for electricity. The science of costing is relevant for policy makers.

 

There is an intriguing comparison of “bottom up” costing for CO2 reduction and “top down” costing.  Bottom up is the typical engineer’s approach – considering costs of using technologies on hand for reducing CO2 production in each sector of the economy – cars, blast furnaces, power plants. Top down costing relates the cost of CO2 reduction to prices and incomes. The methods lead to similar results – a cost of $100 billion for the US to reduce CO2 by 30% from 2012 to 2025. This similarity comes despite negative cost technologies found in the early years using the engineering approach. Nordhaus notes that bottom up works with a finite group of sectors, whereas the top down approach is economy wide.

 

Nordhaus moves on to map the global cost – yes the cost for the whole world economy - of meeting temperature targets with full global participation and then with 50% global participation. With full global participation and 100% efficient policies the 2% target from the earlier Copenhagen world meeting is plausible. With 50% global participation, achieving that target becomes virtually impossible because the percentage of global income needed rises so much more steeply. For example, if India does not participate, other countries would have to pay more to reach the global target – and so on. The costs rise if the policies are inefficient. No country is efficient. Policies are a mixture of regulations, energy taxes and green subsidies. For example, US car fuel efficiency standards are inefficient in that they only apply to new cars. Unless all countries participate and policies are more efficient the goal of 2% will be hard. But Nordhaus urges that the world does not give up – striving for those policies, realistic goals and social mechanisms to encourage economic efficiency and high participation.

 

Part III about costing ends with Chapter 16. This is about the economics of discounting – how to take into account the fact that over time the costs shrink. Comparing how much paid now is worth thirty years ahead is what he explains. And he sets his own 4% discounting against others used and shows the various results. There is no lack of acknowledged uncertainties here. But Nordhaus’ arguments and explanations are the best economic science of the moment. That deserves to be heard.

 

Part IV turns to examine the policies and institutions that fit with this science that has been set out and explained. Chapter 17 sets out the historical basis and the scientific basis for the 2% - and now 1.5% - temperature target. Chapter 18 explains the case for doing a cost to benefit analysis for policy and institution creation.

 

With the scene set, Chapter 19 is entitled “The Central Role of Carbon Taxes.”

Nordhaus shows the effect of various carbon prices and their effects on carbon intensive goods versus non-intensive goods. Following his evidence he sums up:

 

“They [carbon prices] provide strong incentives to reduce emissions; they do so in an evenhanded way; they affect all aspects of the economy from production to innovation; and they economize on the information that people need to make efficient decisions” - page 227.

 

Chapter 20 examines national policies and a cap-and-trade versus straight carbon tax.  Both strategies require legislation. The similarities and differences are shown and hybrids of the two are considered. For Nordhaus, the straight carbon tax ends as his best option with cap-and-trade for those with high tax aversion. Chapter 21 examines the international policies and institutions, beginning with a short summary of international agreements.

 

Chapter 22 entitled “Balance Sheet on Alternative Approaches” examines a range of alternatives to carbon tax. Some of these are useful and complementary. Things such as tax breaks for green technologies are considered. Finally, he notes the syndrome that people tend to buy a cheaper car in the face of evidence that over a modest time a slightly more costly car will save more by use of less gasoline. That is part of the policy challenge. In the end Nordhaus is clear that: “The shortcomings of relying primarily on regulations are severe …” (page 272) He sums up the evidence with three reasons. First, reducing emissions would require dealing with technologies over the entire economy and governments do not have enough information to do this. Secondly, “Regulatory policies alone cannot come close to solving the global warming problem by themselves.” And “Third, regulations can be very costly or even counterproductive if they are not carefully designed.” He adds: “Given the unfavourable record of the regulatory approach, you might wonder why governments universally employ regulatory tools when they have been shown to be so inefficient. Studies have shown again and again that gasoline taxes are more efficient than regulations in reducing gasoline consumption or in reducing CO2 emissions from transportation.” So regulations would be needed at every level – to regulate car, truck and airline emissions and a ship’s emissions and a refrigerator’s emissions and a home gas furnace’s emissions. On the other hand, a carbon tax is just universal.

 

Chapter 23 turns from the challenge of achieving a limit of 2 degrees in temperature rise and faces the fact that the underlying CO2 problem stems from an economy based on burning fossil fuels. What new technologies might replace fossil fuels and how would people be persuaded to move over to them. Wind, solar and geothermal are available. The issue is their cost competitiveness. Wind is 50% more expensive and with limited capacity in the US. Geothermal is marginally more than wind. Solar is twice as costly as wind. Nuclear is a matter of public concern over risks. Carbon sequestering is undeveloped and is costly. There follows a sobering reflection on the science of technological changes of the scale required and about the process of innovation and the challenge of that. Chapter 24 reflects on the critics of the science of climate change. History reminds us that there can be a consensus but it might need to be changed if new evidence emerges. However, we go with the best we have at the time. Chapter 25 examines public opinion. Most people are poorly informed about public affairs. People rely on the experts of the groups they adhere to. The issue has an entrenched political partisan dimension despite Nordhaus’ argument that a carbon tax should bridge the US partisan divide.

 

Finally chapter 26 looks at obstacles to climate change policies – like self-interest in an economic area, such as creating unemployed coal miners in the USA.  I find it sobering. In Canada, Alberta cannot imagine a future without shipping tar sands oil down pipelines.



TOP   Click:   Green 
Copyright 2019 All Rights Reserved