Green
Whither Democracy & Work?
                        July 2019


Click square for index Green


There seems to be no end to depressing books to read. Gwynne Dyer’s Growing Pains: The Future of Democracy (and Work), Scribe, 2018 tries to put a positive face on the present lows of democracies and the disappearing work for many. This is not a forceful book, but Dyer shines a light on parts of our era of the sixth extinction and climate change. And these parts are useful to know. Also, he writes well. Yet I had to add to Dyer's ending from another UK book of this year - as the reader will discover!

 

A Giant Orange Canary – a reference to Trump - heads an introductory chapter that touches on the emergence of regressive and anti-immigrant leadership and contenders for leadership not just in the USA but in Holland, Denmark, Poland, Hungary and France, and in the Brexit nationalistic and anti-immigrant movement in the UK. Dyer contends that anger at the lack of decent jobs powers the shift to populism. Contrary to Trump’s stories, US jobs did not go to immigrants, nor to workers overseas. US jobs stayed in the USA. But they moved south and west leaving angry people to vote for Trump. Then jobs started to be replaced by computers and robots –  automation – but still within the USA. And this automation will continue, posing a growing challenge for which the book later, somewhat half-heartedly, suggests a remedy.

 

Anti-immigrant sentiment plays a big role in promoting Trump-like populists in Europe, and racism played a role in the UK Brexit vote. I suspect racism played a bigger role in the USA than Dyer may be aware of. Trump’s constant undermining of the first black President was a cry for votes from white nationalists.

 

Dyer introduces the reader to a possible response to the disappearing middle class jobs and middle class. Universal Basic Income, UBI, could diffuse the anger and provide dignity. He refers to several experiments with UBI, including the all-party trial of UBI in Ontario now terminated by the Ford populist government after its election Spring 2018.

 

However, some anger surely also comes from the sense of unfairness about the concentration of wealth into the hands of a tiny percentage of national populations. This anger sent out the “occupy wall street” movement of a few years past. Government bailouts for banks and auto manufacturers, leaving misled home mortgage holders hanging out to dry was transparently unfair.

 

Dyer argues that some of the new democracies shifted backwards to thugs as usual - in Philippines and Egypt – but that these thugs were at least new thugs, and that some to and fro is to be expected when a democracy starts. For the Philippines, maybe. But the end of Egypt’s democratically elected president seems to have more to do with a danger perceived by powerful allies (the US?) that this elected president was carving his own direction for Egypt and deciding which countries would be its allies. Gwyn is right that democracy is desirable as the best way to deal with a world of humanity’s self-inflicted challenges – nuclear weapon spread, climate change and automation. These are issues he explored next.

 

Chapter 2 turns to the challenge of nuclear weapon spread from N. Korea and Iran, and the dangerous fact that US President Trump has a virtual free hand in the foreign policy area including the pressing of the nuclear button. Trump’s dabbling into N. Korea’s nuclear program has been on/off photo-op meetings with outrageous twitter comments. Dyer argues N. Korea fears the US ability to deliver a massive nuclear strike against it that can only be contained by a capability to strike back. The war with the South is still waiting to be brought to a successful end. Dyer predicts that in the end, N. Korea like Pakistan and others that felt vulnerable without nukes will get the weapons and a scarier world will learn again to struggle on with another nuclear power.

 

Dyer joins European leaders in regretting Trump’s pulling the US out of the agreement with Iran that the UN group seeking to prevent the spread of nuclear weapons had agreed upon. He raises concerns about nuclear war given hostility towards Iran and given Trump’s close links with Saudi Arabia and the oil there. My early 2018 work on the war in Yemen showed the invasion led by Saudi Arabia fighting in deadlock with Houthi rebels supposedly backed by Iran. This indicates to me that this quite separate war issue seems to have become tangled in Trump’s position against the nuclear program. Dyer shows Iran was successfully contained by the agreement entered into by former President Obama. So Dyer hopes that the world will avert the human disaster from a renewed Korean war or the dangers of a war against Iran. He claims to fear the arrival of populist politics in the world far more.

 

His third chapter looks at Brexit, the EU, and the issue of immigrants. Dyer reminds us that the EU is more than a trading agreement. It is a political vehicle designed to preserve peace in Europe via democratic principles. That is now threatened. In the EU Trump is largely perceived as a foe. Electoral support for anti EU parties rose in France and Germany. Poland and Hungary are anti-immigrant and anti-Muslim. And the UK is leaving the EU. Other than in England and France, EU voters in post-industrial areas voted as before. Immigration was a big issue everywhere on account of the huge numbers of Syrian refugees.

 

Dyer tracks the UK relationship with the EU. Britain noticed the trade dimension in the 1960’s but was vetoed by De Gaulle in 63. Conservative PM Heath renegotiated the terms and joined in ‘73. Terms were renegotiated again 2 years later under Labour, then again in ‘84 under PM Thatcher. The UK opted out of the single currency in ‘93, then renegotiated the terms again in 2013. Dyer says Britain is not alone in seeing the follies of the EU bureaucracy, but it is almost totally alone in seeing European unity as an optional project to be reassessed from time to time. The unexpected win of the Brexit vote by the UK nationalists forced the resignation of PM Cameron and forced incoming PM May to become nationalist – against her admitted awareness of the economic benefits of EU membership. Cameron’s referendum was for Conservative party interests. It was poorly planned.

 

Brexit was won by a hair’s breadth. It was divisive: old for; young against; educated against; large cities against; areas with many immigrants against! The US cliff-hanger presidential election that followed Brexit revealed similar sharp patterns among voters. In Brexit there were lies about the EU, about EU bureaucrats’ actions, about the UK costs and about impending immigrants from the EU. Dyer gives supporting details of the distorted tales of each player in the Brexit campaign.

 

At the end of this chapter, Dyer returns to include the unexpected election of Trump in the US. He examines factors supposedly responsible: free trade; globalization; rich-poor gap; immigrant numbers; automation; social media. Dyer focuses on the great anger manifest in the campaigns to assess the main factor. In Brexit there was an anti-immigrant and racist component in the discourse, but it was not the issue. Dyer says that un-employment and under-employment provided the essential fuel for these populist successes.

 

The thought provoking and different middle chapter 4, Democracy: default made politics, mixes Dyers journalistic experiences around the end of the Cold War with the anthropology of ancient egalitarian tribes to lead to an embedded human tendency towards equality, now enabled by mass communication. The vulnerability of democracy in an era of resurgent populism need not be over played, he says. There is more to democracy than a few Greek city-states and the French and US revolutions.

 

Dyer reminds us of the end of the Cold War in 1990 and the amazing number of new democracies that emerged. In the 1980s Filipinos got rid of dictator Marcos and South Korea, Thailand and Taiwan flipped to democracy. Subsequently, South Africa went democratic. True, much history is built out of back-to-back hierarchies of power and privilege, but anthropological circles agree that earlier bands of hunter-gatherers were intensely egalitarian.

 

Around 1991 anthropologists developed theories that egalitarian behavior had evolved by the majority of the group acting collectively to curb dominating individuals. Such early egalitarian groups disappeared along the Nile, in the Fertile Crescent, along the Indus and in the Yellow River valley 5-10,000 years ago. Empires arrived. Dyer says food production and populations soared. Social customs checking ambitious individuals collapsed. Inequalities soared. Centralized leadership arrived. But the myths of the lost golden ages – the Gardens of Eden – remained. The arrival of the major religions around 2000 years ago declared an absolute spiritual equality of all believers. In the everyday life of ordinary human beings egalitarianism never went away despite the reality of hierarchy, militarization and oppression.

 

Dyer argues that the arrival of the printing press in Europe and widespread literacy brought an ability to discuss means and ends and to reach collective decisions across large numbers of people. This happened in the American colonies. A constitution recaptured egalitarian values, along with means for them to function in a mass democracy. Several revolutions later, and after a war against fascists, with limitations and backslidings, sorts of democracies have arrived in all but the Muslim world.

 

Dyer ends the chapter saying that a large number of people have their old egalitarian freedom back after 5,000 years. He continues with drama. Yes, 7 billion people in the world is too many. Yes, there is climate change. Yes there is a sixth extinction. Yes we are running close to the wind. But consider how much worse we could have made it.

“… I don’t think a man as ignorant and self-indulgent as Donald Trump is going to destroy American democracy, let alone that populism is going to do it worldwide.” This reader remains uneasy - I hope Dyer is right.

 

Chapter 5 is an interesting critique of Trump. That leads to thoughts about what led people to vote for this person. That in turn leads to what must be done post-Trump to allow wisdom rather than populism to feed democracy. Dyer notes Trump’s win was not a landslide. Voting patterns were very similar to previous elections. Trump won by taking 3 states from the democrats by very narrow margins at the Electoral College. 12% of Bernie Sanders’ supporters voted for Trump in these states. Clinton still had the most voters earning less than $50,000. But there was a 16% swing from her by voters earning less than $30,000. Dyer says this suggests an economic root.

 

Dyer notes Trump was no ordinary candidate. He was a serial liar. At rallies 15 September to 6 November the Toronto Star recorded 560 false statements – 20 per day. He spouted casual racism, misogyny and anti-Semitism. He had filed bankruptcy 6 times. He refused to reveal tax returns. He is vulgar, vain and narcissistic. Dyer compares him with the former Italian Prime Minister Silvio Berlusconi, noting that, if so, the US is in trouble, but not terminal trouble. Trump suffers from the same lack of any strategy other than self-promotion. Why did honest Americans vote for him?

 

Trump enjoyed $5.6 billion worth of free media coverage by making himself newsworthy - more than all the other contenders had when combined. Dyer quotes 18 of his most egregious statements – then asks again how people voted for him. Only 15% of the wealth generated by the US economy since the 1970’s has gone to workers. The US poor are now worse off than the poor in Canada, Holland or Scandinavia. In contrast, between 1945 and 1980, the bottom 90% earners in the US got 66% of the money generated by the economy. (The top 10% did well with their 33%.) A burst of inflation in the 70s made possible the neo-liberal economic model that Regan promoted in the 1980s. Thereafter controlling inflation became the goal rather than full employment. Globalization in capital and trade was promoted. Shareholder payment took priority from re-investing in the company. Trade union power was broken to allow more flexible hire and fire markets. Wealth would supposedly trickle down to the poor.

 

In fact the only serious benefit was higher incomes for the rich. (Dyer does not comment on higher wealth for the wealthy.) At the same time re-investment rates fell relative to profits and the rate of productivity growth fell too. Between 1979 and 2013 the pay of hourly paid workers rose only 8.6% while productivity rose to 8 times as fast. A major factor driving wages down (and/or job loss) was free trade. And despite other complicating factors, victims see free trade as a large part of the problem.

 

Dyer points out the moral aspect to free trade. Without trade with richer countries it is hard for poor countries to break out of poverty. But there was a third way. Dyer points out that trade was negotiated 1947-1994 under the UN General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs, GATT, allowing national interests to be taken into account. And trade grew 7% a year for 40 years. When GATT became the World Trade Organization, a body taken over by the free marketeers, the annual rate of trade growth fell to half that. Dyer claims financial self-interest is hidden under a cloak of economic policy preference: Keynes’ policies favor the majority and the poor; Hayek’s and Friedman’s favor the rich.

 

Clinton and Obama, like Tony Blair in the UK, followed a “third way” as Blair put it. They were not true to the interests of the poor. People in a modern democracy accept a bit of flexibility in the supposed equality. Basic needs are covered, people tend to associate with others of the same social and economic class and the reality of broader society is softened by the fiction of equality of opportunity. But if the rich to poor gulf gets too big, the patience of the majority runs out. Dyer says it did so in the US election of 2016. Anger relief is not a good guide for voting.

 

Trump has been all over the political map. He’s neither Republican nor Democrat. “He is the populist voice of the disappointed and frustrated ‘angry white men’ of both sexes …” Dyer worries whether the US would bend to Trump as a dictator. After worrying this reader, he reveals that on balance he feels that unlikely. He also thinks it would take a long time to ruin the US irretrievably. What is important is for a US government post Trump to begin to rectify the huge inequalities and disaffection that made a Trump victory possible – and to do that within one or two election cycles. With that he brings the reader back to the question of what exactly went wrong – the facts.

 

Chapter 6 examines what killed the jobs – globalization or automation. In the US globalization – that meant free trade to Trump – was a big issue. People did not want more of the same. True, free trade pushed US wages down, but did it take jobs? Overall, the impact on jobs was in fact small. This is because trade is a small part, 27%, of the US GDP. It is much larger for other countries and 84% for Germany. So for the US, free trade was not a big job killer – nor was immigration.  The neo-liberal economic order cut pay and in the early days “off-shoring” did move some jobs as factories closed in the US and opened in Mexico or China. By the 1990s IT jobs were created abroad to serve US businesses and it is not clear that they replaced US jobs or were an alternative to more automation in the US itself. In sum, the largest number of jobs was lost in the early 21st century and few were exported. A third of US jobs were lost in the last 30 years. US productivity is now twice what it was in 1979. The presumption is that this results from automation. Of 7 million US manufacturing jobs lost, 5 million went to automation.

 

Other jobs moved within the US to the US sunbelt – south and west - where unions were weaker. The jobs left behind the “rust belt” that voted in Trump. But the destruction of the once beautifully productive Detroit was not by automation. It was a victim of inequality. Injustices were suffered by hundreds of Afro Americans that migrated to the factories of the North during WWII. The 1967 burning of the inner city in race riots marked the beginning of decay followed by “white flight” and a drift to the suburbs. Then from 1970 wages failed to keep up with rising productivity. Much the same happened in other industrial cities. One might think that linking wages to productivity again and a few other changes would deal with the frustration and anger that got trump elected. But the roots go deeper.

 

Car making has now been hit by automation, and more is to come. For the past 3 generations making cars has been the largest industrial occupation on the planet. Now automation has caused a fall in manufacturing employment. With fewer employees, it is no longer significant where cars are made – whether one pays the few Mexican, Chinese or US workers. Indeed manufacturing can move back to the US for convenience at little cost. But more change is to come.

 

Countries are ending gasoline or diesel cars within 20 years. Oil exporting countries will find incomes falling – no doubt with political consequences. Oil jobs will be lost but others in the green electrical industry will likely be created. Some jobs will be lost because electric vehicles are simpler to produce. But a bigger challenge comes from driverless vehicles.

 

Dyer says driverless vehicles will become public utilities, summoned when they are needed. A privately owned car, parked for 95% of the time will become a dispensable luxury. This, rather than a cheaper taxi, is the aim of the Über business model. Private ownership of cars will fall, so that by 2025 half of today’s number of owners will want to own a car. That number could fall to ¼ - about the fraction of the cars presently on the road at any given time. The result would be an effective end to the remaining car manufacturing jobs. The changes go further – drivers of conventional buses and taxis, and truckers and van drivers will all loose jobs. Town parking land will become available for housing. So maybe there will be some short term construction jobs?

 

This job loss is occurring across other changes in industries. It is not limited to manual work. Processes to research legal precedents or keep medical records are being automated – insurance claims are being evaluated by artificial intelligence! Any job with routine work can be automated. So a new question arises: who can buy a product or service if there are no jobs out there paying people money?

 

Dyer notes in passing Henry Ford’s wisdom: employees ought to be a company’s best customers. Henry doubled workers’ wages and cut workweeks and sold Fords! But where are the Henry Fords? Most research on job loss and job creation is pessimistic. Twenty years from now we are looking at a 35-40% jobless rate. That is more than enough to generate the anger and frustration to vote in another few Trumps.

 

Dyer reminds us of the terrible employment situation pre WWII. After that war aggressive action generated various forms of a welfare state. (Dyer manages to remind us in this section that the health care system in the US is the most expensive model in the World.) Compared to that time, the present challenges are not so great. Some thinkers have raised the old idea of Universal Basic Income again. It can reduce the anger by reducing the income gap and put money into pockets to keep purchasing power afloat. It is part of how to maintain social justice and political stability in a democracy where capital (automation) is replacing labour.

 

Dyer warns not to confuse this with the various attempts to streamline the delivery of other state benefits into a single package. A Universal Basic Income goes to everyone, rich or poor, as a matter of right. I see it as like Canada’s Old Age Security – but hopefully more sizable! Unlike welfare there is no stigma. On the other hand, when those presently working are asked to rank various possibilities, UBI comes out near the bottom of preferences.

 

Dyer foresees a major transition in society to one where work is lessened. It is not a society of workers and non-workers but rather one with shorter hours of work all round. The industrial revolution was an angry turbulent time. Finding money and respect for people without those old jobs is the challenge. In the end it may be UBI. For now it may be some old patches: higher minimum wage; stronger trade unions; linkage between productivity and pay; unemployment and welfare payments that do not vanish with the first low-paid casual job.

 

And so to the last chapter, Growing Pains, that brings us full circle with a review and some filling out. Dyer returns to how humans order society and their notion of equality, stating that equality among adult males is a long-standing human tradition. But it vanished during empires: human height fell; epidemic diseases grew; populations went up, but lifespan likely went down. By the 14th -16th centuries CE most of the global population was in four Old World civilizations. The Indian, Islamic and Chinese (with effects from Mogul invasion) plus Renaissance Europe.

 

Europe produced “enlightenment” and notions of “fraternity” that became equality and that led to the first democratic revolutions in the 18th century. Then the Industrial Revolution began. From 1750 to 2010 the population increased tenfold, the land farmed went from 7% to 40%, the sixth extinction began, atmospheric CO2 went from 280ppm to 400ppm, wars became more destructive and nuclear weapons were dropped on two cities.

 

Dyer finds re-assurance that over those 300 years slavery and serfdom ended, traditional empires vanished and a beginning was made on gender equality. Many countries ended the death penalty, torture is illegal but tolerated in places, major powers do not fight directly, and there is a UN and an International Court of Justice. Dyer says we are a young species in a millennia-long experiment called civilization. It may succeed with “mutual respect, global cooperation, limited intervention in natural systems, and a democratic political culture that puts a high value on equality and restraint – all the things the cynics sneer at.” Or it may fail.

 

Dyer views the Soviet era as a quest for an absolute equality. He says the learning from it is that some degree of inequality must be tolerated to have liberty and prosperity flourish. The necessary political will to respond to the present challenges can best come from a democratic society. The threat of angry populism comes from a concern about equality. It does bring some risk of fascism. 

 

Dyer returns to thoughts on Trump as the “canary in the coalmine” revealing the anger in minorities. His policy seems linked to undoing Obama’s legacy issues. Clinton had entertained thoughts about some type of UBI in her campaign, but dropped them. Dyer says objections to UBI come from fiscal and moral concern. Fiscal, because the sums of money involved are big. A related practical or moral concern is that it would destroy the will to get up and go out to work.

 

Dyer shows that there are offsetting sums of money available. Some state benefits would no longer be needed - such as unemployment insurance and pensions. Using the brief Ontario experiment, such previous benefits accounted for 40% of the cost. Then some funds would come from income tax because the additional UBI would raise some people into a higher tax bracket. The remaining gap would come from creative things like taxing the automation! The moral concern of destroying the will to work can be shown to be small by Dyer’s accounts of a pilot project in Manitoba, and of the Iranian UBI. This is all positive as far as it goes.

 

The moral concern is that without work all meaning and purpose will vanish from people’s lives. Dyer counters this with British data showing that many people find their jobs insignificant or meaningless. He quotes Galbraith’s sarcasm to the effect that leisure is good for the rich and for Harvard professors but very bad for the poor. My own experience is from early retirement. I found it liberating to be able to do some things I had wanted to do. But I do know some retirees who hang onto a little part-time work.

 

The real concern, says Dyer, is preventing Democracy from becoming overwhelmed by the changes of the next couple of decades. And by reducing income equality, UBI would also reduce social ills that might otherwise become major problems - even health and life expectancy. Research supporting that statement is described. Then Dyer leaves us with UBI.


Dyer’s concern is echoed with a twist in another different depressing UK book I read this summer: Harry Leslie Smith, Don’t Let My Past be Your Future,  Constable, 2018.
Smith is a 94-year-old staunch Labour Party supporter who describes a childhood of appalling poverty in post 1929 depression Yorkshire that was only dispelled by World War II.

 

His book told me something I wasn’t aware of.  He became old enough to join the RAF in 1942. In that year the multi-party UK war government commissioned the Beveridge Report. The Report was a blueprint for a post-war Britain in which all facets of the nation would share in its wealth and its work. It called for public healthcare, affordable housing and education for all its citizens. “This report provided a reason – beyond blind patriotism – for the working class to defend Britain ... they were no longer just fighting to defend the entitlements of the elite, but for their own future.” Smith joined the RAF.

 

The Labour Party manifesto for the post-war election in 1945 called out for that kind of Britain. Smith voted for it. I recall that my dad did too but my dad didn’t speak of the grand concept of a post-war inclusive society. The Attlee Labour government won, but struggled to implement it through post-war debt austerity and consequent rationing. Despite Labour losses following 1951, this model held until the Thatcher Conservative government began its days in 1979.

 

Smith’s book calls for a new Beveridge Report for the 21st century to bridge the canyon now separating the top 10% wage earners – and I would add the top 1% national wealth holders – and everyone else. “It must look at ways to combat automation, the sharing economy, democratic decline and the erosion of state services.” I agree. And Smith leaves a more challenging ending to his book than Dyer. .

 


TOP   Click:   Green 
Copyright 2019 All Rights Reserved